top of page

MENU

Trianon Scientific Communication

The 2024 Nobel prize of economy explained

Updated: Oct 18

Why Some Countries Prosper While Others Don't


Have you ever wondered why some countries are rich while others remain poor?

Why do some nations seem to be stuck in poverty while others thrive?

The 2024 Nobel Prize in Economics was awarded to three researchers who have shed light on these very questions. Let's break down their groundbreaking work in simple terms.





The prize was awarded to Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson for their studies on "how institutions are formed and affect prosperity." [1]


But what does that really mean? Let's dive in!


The Big Idea: Institutions matter


Imagine two neighboring towns.

In Town A, there's a fair mayor, honest police, and courts that treat everyone equally.

In Town B, the mayor is corrupt, the police can be bribed, and the courts favor the rich.

Which town do you think will do better in the long run?


If you guessed Town A, you're on the right track! This is the core of what our Nobel laureates discovered, but on a much larger scale - the scale of entire countries.


The Colonial connection


The researchers looked at countries that were colonized by Europeans and noticed something interesting. Some former colonies became rich (like the United States or Australia), while others remained poor (like many countries in Africa or South America). Why?


It all comes down to the type of institutions the colonizers set up:


  1. Inclusive institutions

In some places, colonizers established fair systems that protected property rights, encouraged education, and allowed for economic opportunities for many. These are like our Town A.


  1. Extractive institutions:

In other places, colonizers set up systems designed to exploit resources and the local population, benefiting only a small elite.

These are like our Town B.


Real-world examples


Let's take two real countries: the United States and Mexico.

Both were colonized by Europeans, but they ended up with very different institutions.


  • In the U.S., early settlers established inclusive institutions that protected property rights and encouraged entrepreneurship. This laid the groundwork for long-term prosperity.


  • In Mexico, Spanish colonizers set up more extractive institutions focused on mining precious metals and exploiting indigenous labor. This created a system where wealth was concentrated in the hands of a few, hampering long-term economic growth.


To further illustrate the concepts discussed by Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson, let's look at two African countries: Botswana and Zimbabwe. These neighboring countries have had very different economic trajectories since gaining independence, largely due to their institutional structures.


Botswana: a success story

Botswana has been often cited as an African success story. Here's why:

  • Inclusive institutions: After gaining independence in 1966, Botswana's leaders established relatively inclusive political and economic institutions. They maintained and strengthened the traditional Tswana institutions that encouraged broad-based participation in decision-making.

  • Resource management: Despite discovering diamond deposits, Botswana avoided the resource curse that has plagued many African countries. The government negotiated favorable deals with mining companies and used the revenues to invest in public services, infrastructure, and education.

  • Property rights: Botswana established strong property rights and maintained the rule of law, encouraging both domestic and foreign investment.

  • Result: Botswana has experienced one of the fastest growth rates in per capita income in the world. From being one of the poorest countries at independence, it has transformed into an upper-middle-income country.[2]


Zimbabwe: Challenges of Extractive Institutions

In contrast, Zimbabwe has faced significant economic challenges:

  • Extractive institutions: After gaining independence in 1980, Zimbabwe initially showed promise. However, over time, political institutions became more extractive, concentrating power in the hands of a small elite.

  • Land reform: A controversial land reform program in the early 2000s, while aimed at addressing historical inequalities, was implemented in a way that disrupted agricultural production and property rights, leading to economic instability.

  • Economic policies: The government implemented policies that discouraged foreign investment and led to hyperinflation, severely impacting the country's economic stability.

  • Result: Despite its rich natural resources and initial promise, Zimbabwe has experienced economic decline, with periods of hyperinflation and high unemployment rates.[3]


These examples demonstrate how the quality of institutions can significantly impact a country's economic trajectory. Botswana's more inclusive institutions have contributed to its economic success, while Zimbabwe's more extractive institutions have posed challenges to its economic development.

It's important to note that these situations are complex, with many factors at play beyond just institutional structures. However, they provide real-world illustrations of the principles outlined in the Nobel Prize-winning work of Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson.


The Poverty trap


You might wonder, "If inclusive institutions are so great, why don't poor countries just change their systems?"

Great question! The researchers found that it's not that simple.


Imagine you're the leader of a country with extractive institutions. You and your friends benefit from the current system. Changing to inclusive institutions would be better for the country in the long run, but you'd lose your personal advantages.

Would you do it?


This is what the researchers call a "poverty trap."

Leaders of countries with extractive institutions often have short-term incentives to keep things as they are, even if it means their country remains poor.


A Glimmer of hope: the path to democracy


Despite this gloomy picture, the researchers also found a potential path to positive change. Sometimes, when there's a threat of revolution, leaders may choose to establish democracy as a way to make credible promises of reform.


It's like a parent promising a child, "I'll give you more allowance next week." The child might not believe it. But if the parent sets up a system where the child can decide their own allowance (within reason), that's a promise the child can trust.


Why is it worth a Nobel prize?


Understanding these dynamics helps us grasp why some countries struggle to develop and why simply giving aid isn't always enough. It shows that to truly help developing nations, we need to focus on building strong, fair institutions.


The work of Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson gives us valuable insights into one of the biggest challenges of our time: reducing the vast differences in income between countries.

By highlighting the crucial role of institutions, they've provided a new lens through which we can view global inequality and work towards solutions.


So next time you hear about economic differences between countries, remember: it might just come down to the type of "town" they've built for themselves over the centuries![1]



 

Kommentarer


bottom of page